Carrying Capacity Network
URGENT ACTION ALERT
Negative Impacts of Immigration--Legal and Illegal Amnesty Threat- & Solutions - CCN Alert!
CCN Alert!
carryingcapacity.org
July, 2022
------In 2017 CCN took the lead in calculating the NET (after subtracting taxes immigrants pay) Costs of LEGAL immigration to U.S. taxpayers
and has formulated SOLUTIONS (see below) to the Negative Impacts of both Illegal and Legal
----- And since 2019 Cis,org has published Compendia demonstrating all of these Negative impacts, see below
Net Costs of Legal Immigration to the U.S. Taxpayer
carryingcapacity.org 2017
Unsustainable
1.5 Million Annual Legal-Immigrant Influx
Costs
U.S. Taxpayers $330 Billion NET per Year
Federal
Deficit Faces a $3.3 Trillion Net Hit in Next Decade,
Without
a Reduction in the 1.5 Million Annual Legal-Immigrant Inflow
More
than 5.9 Million Native-Born American Workers Displaced Since 2005
Had
Annual Legal-Immigrant Influx Been Cut to 150,000 per Year Since
2005
Net
Costs to U.S. Taxpayers Would Be $150 Billion per Year at Present
carryingcapacity.org 2017
and from CIS.ORG
A Compendium of Recent Academic Work Showing Negative Impacts of Immigration
By Jason Richwine on June 27, 2022
[Editor's Note: This is the third and most up-to-date edition of the compendium. It was originally published in 2019 and then revised in 2020.]
Introduction
Is there a scholarly consensus that immigration benefits all Americans? Listening to advocates and their allied media, one might assume so. Vox once ran this headline: “There's no evidence that immigrants hurt any American workers.” A writer for Forbes claimed that immigration restrictionists “are on the wrong side of history and the wrong side of social science”. Reason’s Shikha Dalmia has claimed that George Borjas is “literally the only economist of any repute who questions the economic benefits of immigration”.
The purpose of this compendium is to dispel such self-serving myths. The truth is that the costs and benefits of immigration are routinely measured, weighed, and debated in academic journals. No fair reading of the literature could conclude that immigration has only benefits — or only costs, for that matter. A 2016 review by the National Academies of Sciences, Engineering, and Medicine demonstrated the mixed effects of immigration, as have dozens of studies appearing since that time. This compendium uses the National Academies as a starting point, then summarizes a sample of subsequently published papers that find costs associated with immigration. These papers address the labor market impact of immigration as well as broader effects.
The National Academies’ 2016 Review
Chapters 4 and 5 of the National Academies’ book-length report review the theoretical and empirical research on how immigration affects wages and employment. Anyone who takes the time to read this material will understand that immigration is costly to certain groups of Americans. For example, Table 5-2 from the report lists several major studies measuring immigration’s impact on wages. Notice the negative values in the “Wage Effect” column:
Unfortunately, not everyone has done the reading. The economist-activist Esther Duflo once told a whopper about the National Academies’ report. According to her, the report “summarized maybe hundreds of studies, and they all come to the conclusion that the effect of low-skilled migration on low-skilled wages is zero.” It is these types of assertions, thoroughly unmoored from reality, that fuel the impression of consensus about immigration’s benefits.
Recent Studies
Since the National Academies’ report was published in 2016, academics have continued to produce papers finding costs associated with immigration. A curated list of these recent papers is provided below. Please note that the authors are mainstream academics writing for mainstream outlets. Harvard’s George Borjas, who was alleged to be “the only economist” to publish these types of studies, clearly has a lot of company. Like Borjas, these authors usually stress that they have found both costs and benefits. One-sided claims about immigration are rarely true.
In each of the following paper summaries, I focus on the immigration aspects of the paper, draw out policy implications, and link to related CIS research whenever helpful.
Wage and Employment Effects
Anthony
Edo, “The
Impact of Immigration on the Labor Market”, Journal of
Economic Surveys, Vol. 33, No. 3, July 2019.
This
review paper is similar in content to the National Academies’
chapters, but it takes a more international perspective. After
considering over 50 studies of immigration in developed countries,
the author concludes that “immigration can create winners and
losers among the native-born workers.” Because low-skill
immigration tends to make low-skill natives the “losers”
and high-skill natives the “winners”, rising inequality
is a natural consequence. This conclusion stands in stark contrast
to the advocates’ position that “there is no evidence
that immigrants hurt any American workers.” While some
Americans gain from immigration, others certainly do lose.
Joseph
Price, Christian vom Lehn, and Riley Wilson, “The
Winners and Losers of Immigration: Evidence from Linked Historical
Data”, NBER Working Paper No. 27156, May 2020.
This
paper acknowledges the winner-loser framework right in its title.
The authors use genealogical data to track millions of men between
decennial censuses in the early 20th century. Following these
individuals allows the authors to improve upon past research that
focused only on community-level impacts of immigration. They find
that older and higher-skilled workers were the “winners”
— their incomes tended to go up when immigrants entered their
local labor market. By contrast, younger and less-skilled workers
were the “losers” — they were more likely to move
away and suffer income losses as a result of immigration.
In
the modern-day context, CIS has emphasized that immigration tends to
have strong disemployment effects on the youngest and least-skilled
Americans of all: teenagers.
David
A. Jaeger, Joakim Ruist, and Jan Stuhler, “Shift-Share
Instruments and the Impact of Immigration”, NBER Working
Paper No. 24285, February 2018.
Several
studies try to isolate the impact of immigration on wages by
comparing cities with different levels of immigration. The problem
is that immigrants do not choose destination cities randomly. If
they choose cities that have rising wages, the negative impact of
immigration may be obscured.
This paper shows that
a common “instrumental variables” technique to deal with
that problem still unintentionally captures more than just the
initial impact of immigration. When a local area experiences an
influx of immigrants, the wage goes down for a time, but then it
rises back toward equilibrium as more businesses come in or other
workers leave. Since immigrants tend to go to the same places year
after year, the instrumental-variables technique captures both the
negative short-term wage effect and
the positive "catch-up" wage effect from earlier waves of
immigrants. As a result, all of the short-term wage effects
estimated using this method appear less negative than they really
are.
The authors of this paper provide a long list
of prior studies that underestimate negative wage effects because of
this faulty method. Giovanni Peri, an economist famous for
downplaying the negative impact of immigration, has 12 different
papers on the list.
Michael
Amior and Alan Manning, “Monopsony
and the Wage Effects of Migration”, CEP Discussion Paper
No. 1690, May 2021.
In
the standard model first developed by George Borjas, immigrants
produce small economic gains for natives (an “immigration
surplus”) but do so by lowering the wages of competing
workers. The model is built on the assumption of “perfect
competition” in the labor market, meaning that employers
compete for labor until the wage is bid up to equal the workers’
value added. But what happens if the assumption of perfect
competition is relaxed?
The authors of this paper
argue that various legal and cultural barriers prevent immigrants
from moving between jobs as easily as natives do. With less
competition among employers to hire workers, immigration could
reduce the ability of workers to demand a wage that reflects the
full value of their labor. If so, both the surplus and the
corresponding wage reductions would increase in magnitude.
L.
Jason Anastasopoulos, George J. Borjas, Gavin G. Cook, and Michael
Lachanski, “Job
Vacancies and Immigration: Evidence from the Mariel Supply Shock”,
Journal of Human Capital, Vol. 15, No. 1, 2021.
It
may seem that the Mariel Boatlift (summarized here
by CIS) has been studied to death, but this is an innovative paper.
It uses a database of historical job listings to establish that job
vacancies for low-skill workers in Miami declined after a sudden
wave of Cuban refugees arrived in the city in 1980. The implication
is that the labor market was not able to immediately adjust to the
influx of new workers.
Christian
Dustmann, Uta Schönberg, and Jan Stuhler, “Labor
Supply Shocks, Native Wages, and the Adjustment of Local
Employment”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 132, No.
1., 2017.
Maria
Forthun Hoen, “Immigration
and the Tower of Babel: Using Language Barriers to Identify
Individual Labor Market Effects of Immigration”, Labour
Economics, Vol. 65, 2020.
These
two papers analyze immigration surges in different countries but
come to similar conclusions. In the first paper, a change in
commuting policy led to a sudden increase in Czech workers in a
border area of Germany. The result was lower wages and employment
levels for natives, particularly for those who were older and had
less attachment to the labor force. In the second paper, an
expansion of the EU labor market caused a surge of immigration to
Norway. Wages for young workers fell in the most affected
industries, and workers of all ages — especially older ones —
experienced declines in employment and increases in disability
enrollment.
Although these two papers focus on
Europe, they have important implications for U.S. policy. As CIS has
argued,
the tight labor market in the U.S. in 2019 led employers to recruit
from marginalized groups such as high school dropouts and the
disabled. Expanding immigration in a tight labor market could
short-circuit that employer outreach.
Michael
Amior, “The
Contribution of Immigration to Local Labor Market Adjustment”,
CEP Discussion Paper No. 1678, September 2021.
Why
don’t more Americans leave economically depressed places and
move to the parts of the U.S. where more jobs are available? One
answer, according to this paper, is that foreign immigration crowds
them out. New immigrants tend to settle in high-employment areas,
reducing the potential rewards for natives who move there. This
phenomenon again illustrates how immigration can limit the
opportunities for down-and-out natives to benefit from economic
growth.
Javier
Ortega and Gregory Verdugo, “Who
Stays and Who Leaves? Immigration and the Selection of Natives
Across Locations”, Journal of Economic Geography, Vol. 22,
No. 2, March 2022.
George
J. Borjas and Anthony Edo, “Gender,
Selection into Employment, and the Wage Impact of Immigration”,
NBER Working Paper No. 28682, February 2022. Both
of these papers show that immigration in France has imposed downward
pressure on wages and encouraged natives to move away from
high-immigration areas or leave the labor force entirely. Because
the natives who exit tend to be less-skilled, the wage impact of
immigration on a particular area may be understated if researchers
do not take into account the new workforce composition.
Joan
Monras, “Local
Adjustment to Immigrant-Driven Labor Supply Shocks”,
Journal of Human Capital, Vol. 15, No. 1, 2021.
This
is another paper that demonstrates how internal migration can
partially disguise longer-term labor market effects of immigration.
After the Mariel boatlift initially caused wages to decline in
Miami, the labor market returned to equilibrium. However, about half
of the adaptation can be ascribed to low-skill workers moving away
from (or declining to move to) Miami.
Bin
Xie, “The
Effects of Immigration Quotas on Wages, the Great Black Migration,
and Industrial Development”, IZA Discussion Paper No.
11214, December 2017.
Just
as economists have studied sudden surges in immigration to assess
the labor market effects, the results of sudden restrictions on
immigration are also instructive. According to this analysis,
restrictive immigration laws in the 1920s raised manufacturing wages
and drew black migrants from the South into northern factories. This
result provides further support for the theory that immigration
deters natives from moving into emerging labor
markets.
Interestingly, immigration restriction
also appears to have slowed the growth of electric-powered assembly
lines, which illustrates how the relationship between skills and
technology has changed over time. Low-skill workers were once needed
to man the assembly lines that displaced skilled artisans. Today,
technology generally advances with skilled workers — e.g.,
computer programmers in Silicon Valley. (See the Brunello et
al.
paper listed below for more on this point.)
Ran
Abramitzky, Philipp Ager, Leah Boustan, Elior Cohen, and Casper W.
Hansen, “The
Effect of Immigration Restrictions on Local Labor Markets: Lessons
from the 1920s Border Closure”, American Economic Journal:
Applied Economics, forthcoming.
This
paper also finds that 1920s immigration restrictions benefited rural
Americans who migrated into cities to replace lost labor. In
contrast, farmers mechanized rather than attempting to recruit new
workers.
Amy
Wax and Jason Richwine, “Low-Skill
Immigration: A Case for Restriction”, American Affairs,
Winter 2017.
The
authors combine the “top-down” Census Bureau data on
native job losses with “bottom-up” ethnographic research
on employer preferences for immigrant labor. They make a strong
qualitative case that businesses use immigrants to replace natives
in their low-skill workforces.
In 2019, CIS
published a follow-up
report that focused on Equal Employment Opportunity Commission
cases in which employers are accused of favoring immigrant workers
over native workers. The details of these cases are consistent with
the claim that employers use immigration to depress wages and
working conditions.
Maria
Hoen, Simen Markussen, and Knut Roed, “Immigration
and Economic Mobility”, Journal of Population Economics,
2021.
Using
administrative data from Norway, the authors find that low-skill
immigration has reduced social mobility, causing inequality to
increase. Interestingly, they connect their findings to the politics
of immigration. Opposition to immigration from lower classes in
Norway arises not necessarily from “bigotry”, but as a
rational response to their weakened economic position.
David
Neumark and Cortnie Shupe, “Declining
Teen Employment: Minimum Wages, Other Explanations, and Implications
for Human Capital Investment”, Labour Economics, Vol. 59,
2019.
The
primary focus of this paper is the minimum wage, but it finds some
role for immigration in reducing teen employment. In contrast, the
authors find only minimal evidence that teens voluntarily left the
labor market because the economic returns to a high school diploma
had increased.
Anthony
Edo and Hillel Rapoport, “Minimum
Wages and the Labor Market Effects of Immigration”, Labour
Economics, Vol. 61, December 2019.
This
paper uses state variation in minimum wage laws to show that
immigrants tend to lower the wages and employment levels of the
natives with whom they compete most directly. Specifically, natives
suffer greater wage and employment losses due to low-skill
immigration in states with lower minimum wages. Whether increasing
the minimum wage would be wise policy is beyond the scope of the
paper, but it does show once again that immigrants and natives are —
at least to a large extent — substitutes
in the labor market.
John
Bound, Guarav Khanna, and Nicolas Morales, “Understanding
the Economic Impact of the H-1B Program on the U.S”, in
High-Skilled
Migration to the United States and Its Economic Consequences,
Eds. Gordon H. Hanson, William R. Kerr, and Sarah Turner, University
of Chicago Press, 2018.
General
equilibrium models can be highly sensitive to assumptions. It
sometimes seems that one can build a model to prove virtually any
proposition. In this case, however, the model confirms basic
economic theory: High-skill immigration in the 1990s lowered the
wage for competing native workers but reduced consumer prices and
increased corporate profits, again illustrating the trade-offs
inherent to immigration policy. Consumers and corporations win,
while some workers lose.
Giorgio
Brunello, Elisabetta Lodigiani, and Lorenzo Rocco, “Does
Low-skilled Immigration Increase Profits? Evidence from Italian
Local Labour Markets”, Regional Science and Urban
Economics, Vol. 85, November 2020.
Though
its results are likely underestimated due to use of the
instrumental-variables technique discussed in the Jaeger et
al.
paper listed above, this paper finds the usual result that low-skill
immigration reduces wages and increases profits in affected
industries. The authors speculate that low-skill immigration has
retarded Italy’s transition to a more high-tech
economy.
There is an interesting parallel here to
U.S. agriculture, where CIS research has found that immigration
delays
mechanization of the harvest. (Also see the Abramitzky et
al.
paper above.)
Simone
Bertoli and Steven Stillman, “All
That Glitters Is Not Gold: Wages and Education for U.S. Immigrants”,
Labour Economics, Vol. 61, December 2019.
Education
generally correlates with earnings, but the relationship is weaker
among immigrants. This paper finds that when a highly-educated
immigrant is selected at random, 25 percent of the time he or she
will have lower
earnings than a less-educated immigrant who is also selected at
random. The corresponding figure for high- versus less-educated
natives is about 14 percent. “Conferring a pivotal role to
education in the selection of migrants might fail to induce a
substantial increase in their average quality, and it might even
potentially backfire,” the authors warn. For one thing, these
allegedly “skilled” workers could end up competing with
less-educated natives.
The findings are consistent
with several reports published by CIS. First, despite their faster
educational gains, recent immigrants have not
improved relative to natives on measures of income, poverty, and
welfare consumption. Second, college-educated immigrants are more
likely than college-educated natives to hold low-skill jobs,
especially when the immigrants are from Latin America. Third,
immigrants with foreign
college or advanced degrees score lower on tests of English
literacy, numeracy, and computer operations compared to natives with
the same level of education. Finally, the value
of foreign degrees varies substantially by source country.
Cultural and Political Effects
Kathleen
Kürschner Rauck and Michael Kvasnicka, “The
2015 European Refugee Crisis and Residential Housing Rents in
Germany”, IZA Discussion Paper No. 12047, December
2018.
Kathleen
Kürschner Rauck, “Not
in My Backyard! The 2015 Refugee Crisis in Germany”,
Working Paper on Finance 2020/04, September 2020.
These
companion papers fall at the intersection of economics and culture.
They find that the influx of Syrian refugees to Germany lowered
apartment rents and the prices of single-family homes in areas where
the refugees were most concentrated, despite the sheer increase in
people needing housing. The reason is that native Germans did not
wish to live near large numbers of refugees. Immigration changes
host countries in a variety of ways, and these papers offer a rare
quantitative look at how natives sometimes avoid the areas most
affected.
Umair
Ali, “Native
Flight Responses to Immigration: Evidence from K-12 School
Enrollments”, EdWorkingPaper No. 22-579, May 2022.
In
the U.S., a growing immigrant population in a metropolitan area
increases the likelihood that white and black natives will exit the
public schools. The effect is especially strong among white
students, who tend to move over to private schools. By contrast,
Hispanic and Asian students do not leave the public schools. The
author of this paper suggests that “homophily” —
the desire for cultural familiarity — can explain why
immigration appears to be so disruptive to the student body. Lower
levels of immigration would of course mitigate these cultural
disruptions, as CIS has emphasized.
Courtney
Brell, Christian Dustmann, and Ian Preston, “The
Labor Market Integration of Refugee Migrants in High-Income
Countries”, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 34, No.
1, Winter 2020.
Resettling
refugees may be a humanitarian good, but the argument that refugees
are somehow an economic boon to their host nations is dubious. This
paper reviews the evidence that refugees struggle to integrate into
the economies of high-income host nations. In the U.S. specifically,
refugees perform unusually well in finding jobs. However, in line
with their counterparts in other rich nations, U.S. refugees earn
low wages even after 10 years of residency.
CIS
estimated
in 2020 that the average new refugee in the U.S. imposes a fiscal
cost of about $60,000 in lifetime net present value. The
corresponding cost for refugees who enter as adults is $133,000.
Zachary
Ward, “The
Not-So-Hot Melting Pot: The Persistence of Outcomes for Descendants
of the Age of Mass Migration”, American Economic Journal:
Applied Economics, Vol. 12, No. 4, October 2020.
The
idea that Great Wave immigrants of varied nationalities disappeared
into a “melting pot” is an exaggeration. In 1880, large
differences in earnings (as measured by occupational status) existed
among immigrants of different nationalities. By 1940, the
grandchildren of those immigrants still exhibited about half of the
initial differences. Although this paper focuses primarily on Great
Wave immigrants, the author warns that “there are many reasons
to expect the persistence of ethnic gaps to be stronger for more
recent times.”
Indeed, a CIS report
finds that the grandchildren of Mexican immigrants still lag behind
white Americans in education and earnings. Immigration advocates who
brush aside concerns about assimilation need to address this
worrisome evidence.
Dafeng
Xu, “The
Effects of Immigration Restriction Laws on Immigrant Segregation in
the Early Twentieth Century U.S.”, Journal of Comparative
Politics, Vol. 48, No. 2, 2020.
The
ethnic enclaves in which Great Wave immigrants gathered eventually
withered away, leading to less residential segregation. According to
this paper, the process was aided by immigration restriction in the
1920s. The paper finds that residential segregation decreased more
rapidly among the immigrant groups that were most restricted, such
as Italians and Poles. The effect occurred mainly by denying ethnic
enclaves “reinforcements” in the form of new immigrants,
although the author also finds some evidence that return migration
became more likely among enclave residents compared to non-enclave
residents. The results suggest that, to the extent that the “melting
pot” operates, it can be strengthened by limiting
immigration.
Deniz
Gevrek, Cahit Guven, and Z. Eylem Gevrek, “The
Relationship Between Early-life Conditions in the Home Country and
Adult Outcomes Among Child Immigrants in the United States”,
Economics & Human Biology, Vol. 45, 2022.
Immigrants
who arrive in the U.S. as children generally have the benefit of
growing up with institutions that help them integrate into their new
society. However, this paper finds that the infant mortality rate in
the children’s sending country is negatively associated with
their academic performance in U.S. middle schools and with their
subsequent labor market outcomes as adults. The authors argue that
this association is causal. However, even if the relationship is due
to other factors, it is still a sobering reminder that long-term
exposure to U.S. institutions (including costly social programs)
cannot always overcome pre-existing differences. CIS has reflected
on this problem in several papers, including an analysis
of academic tests that include the scores of U.S. immigrants and
their children.
Paola
Giuliano and Marco Tabellini, “The
Seeds of Ideology: Historical Immigration and Political Preferences
in the United States”, NBER Working Paper No. 27238, May
2020.
While
previous papers analyzed the socioeconomic assimilation of Great
Wave immigrants, this one focuses on political assimilation. The
authors find that preferences for redistribution among Americans
today are correlated with the historical presence of immigrants.
Specifically, immigrants seem to have imported the political
ideology of their home countries and then spread those views to
natives. Whether this political effect of immigration is truly
“negative” will depend on one’s own political
views, but remember that any significant political shift, to the
left or to the right, usually involves social disruption.
Crime and Health Effects
Alexander
Billy and Michael Packard, “Crime
and the Mariel Boatlift”, Working Paper, October 2020.
Research
on the Mariel Boatlift usually focuses on the labor market impact.
(See Anastasopoulos et
al.
above.) This paper investigates the impact on crime. Compared to
similar cities, Miami experienced a 41 percent increase in the
murder rate, a 70 percent increase in the rate of robberies, and at
least a 25 percent increase in the rate of property crimes after the
boatlift. The authors caution, however, that extrapolating to
ordinary immigrants would be unjustified, since Fidel Castro added
inmates of prisons and mental hospitals to the ranks of the
Marielitos.
In a 2009 report,
CIS discussed the challenges of measuring immigrant crime. A
follow-up piece
in 2015 summarized recent developments, with particular emphasis on
choosing an appropriate baseline for comparison.
Brandyn
F. Churchill, Andrew Dickinson, Taylor Mackay, and Joseph J. Sabia,
“The
Effect of E-Verify Laws on Crime”, Industrial and Labor
Relations Review, forthcoming.
States
that mandated E-Verify
saw a 7 percent decline in property crime committed by working-age
Hispanics. The authors believe that the decrease in labor market
competition with illegal aliens steered Hispanic citizens toward
work and away from crime.
Mevlude
Akbulut-Yuksel, Naci H. Mocan, Semih Tumen, and Belgi Turan, “The
Crime Effect of Refugees”, NBER Working Paper No. 30070,
May 2022.
The
influx of millions of Syrian refugees into Turkey caused crime to
rise in the most affected provinces, although this study cannot
distinguish between Syrian and Turkish offenders. The authors
theorize that economic competition is one of the drivers of conflict
between the two groups.
Although massive refugee
flows are more associated with Europe, the U.S. may eventually
confront similar issues. For example, when the Biden administration
began accepting tens of thousands of Afghan refugees last year, CIS
warned that vetting
was woefully insufficient. An additional CIS report discussed
evidence that crime
rates among Afghan refugees in Europe are troublingly high.
Whether the U.S. will experience similar refugee crime problems
remains to be seen.
Philipp
Ager, James J. Feigenbaum, Casper Worm Hansen, and Hui Ren Tan, “How
The Other Half Died: Immigration and Mortality in US Cities”,
NBER Working Paper 27480, July 2020.
Analyzing
the aftermath of the 1924 immigration restriction, the authors
develop a measure of “missing immigrants”, meaning the
difference between the actual number of immigrants post-1924 and the
number expected based on pre-1924 trend lines. Cities with more
missing immigrants saw greater declines in infectious-disease
deaths. The authors argue that reduced crowding led to improved
sanitation in cities, boosting the health of immigrants and natives
alike.
The link between overcrowding and disease
became highly salient during the Covid-19 pandemic. As CIS has
shown, household overcrowding contributes to the spread of
respiratory diseases, including
Covid-19, and modern immigration has added
significantly to the overcrowding problem in the U.S. — just
as it did prior to 1924.
Melike
Dedeoğlu, Emrah Koçak, and Zübeyde Şentürk
Uucak, “The
Impact of Immigration on Human Capital and Carbon Dioxide Emissions
in the USA: An Empirical Investigation”, Air Quality,
Atmosphere & Health, Vol. 14, 2021.
This
paper shows that immigration to the U.S. increases the country’s
greenhouse gas emissions. While allowing that mitigating climate
change requires a multi-faceted approach, the authors argue that
policymakers should not ignore the role of immigration when devising
environmental policies. Previous CIS research has made largely the
same
point.
--
And Gavin Newsom's California leads the way in providing taxpayer funded benefits for immigrants:
29 Jun 2022
1,870
The sanctuary state of California will make history by becoming the first state in the nation to give food stamps to illegal aliens.
This week, Gov. Gavin Newsom (D) announced a budget deal with Democrat state legislators that includes providing food stamps, paid for by California’s taxpayers, to illegal aliens 55 and older — the first initiative of its kind in the United States.
An executive with the group Nourish California told the Fresno Bee that the policy is historic for the state, saying, “California is once again making history by removing xenophobic exclusions to our state’s safety net.”
Expansion of the state’s CalFresh food stamps program will cost California’s taxpayers more than $35 million and about 75,000 illegal aliens are expected to enroll every year.
The move comes as Newsom’s budget deal will also ensure that California is the first state in the nation to provide taxpayer-funded health insurance to all of its 3.3 million illegal aliens.
Offering taxpayer-funded health insurance to its entire illegal alien population, the largest in the nation, is expected to cost California’s taxpayers about $2.4 billion annually. The plan is scheduled to begin in 2024.
John Binder is a reporter for Breitbart News. Email him at jbinder@breitbart.com. Follow him on Twitter here.
SOLUTIONS:
--Re: The Pending Mass Alien Amnesty Bill
--
Rep. Salazar’s Mass Alien Amnesty bill is basically mainly a con-job that open borders cheap labor Republicans plus leftist Democrats can enact any time this year UNLESS WE STOP THEM.
So please help CCN stop The largest Illegal Alien Amnesty in U.S. History and end MASS legal immigration!
URGENT: Contact your U.S. Representatives and Senators repeatedly and urge them to oppose any Bill which contains ANY Amnesty Bill provisions or provisions increasing Legal Immigration whatsoever...Insist they support an all-categories included zero-net MORATORIUM on Legal Immigration (which would still allow 150,000 settlers annually) plus a stand-alone Save Title 42 Provision
Also note that CCN is pro-Legal Immigrants but anti-Mass Immigration!
And Most Important to Note:
ONLY pushing CCN's all-categories-included zero Net MORATORIUM on Legal Immigration MAXIMIZES the chances of stopping this Horrendous Amnesty Bill.
Pushing any less restrictive number, as the two National Mass Immigration Management Groups do, will likely result in a Compromise Bill reducing the numbers by just a few hundred thousand at most..... a totally unacceptable result.
Indeed, since those two National Mass Immigration Management groups refuse to support any Moratorium Bill (like Rep. Gosar's e.g.)
THEY ARE DE FACTO ENABLERS OF CONTINUING MASS IMMIGRATION!!
URGENT:Contact your U.S.Representatives and Senators repeatedly and urge them to oppose any Bill which contains ANY Amnesty Bill provisions.
MULTIPLY your Impact by making a Tax-Deductible Donation to Carrying Capacity Network carryingcapacity.org NOW
Frankly, CCN needs money NOW to continue its Activism.!!!
CCN can thereby Intensify its Mobilization of its Activists all over the USA to oppose this bill
Indeed, CCN Activists stopped passage of a Mass Alien Amnesty Bill in December, 2019......
Our Activist Network has Clout!
---
And we reiterate::
ONLY pushing CCN's all-categories-included zero Net MORATORIUM MAXIMIZES the chances of stopping this Horrendous Alien Amnesty Bill.
Pushing any less restrictive number, as the Mass Immigration Management Groups do, will likely result in a Compromise Bill reducing the numbers by just a few Million at most..... a totally unacceptable result.
--
Donations are Tax-Deductible. Help CCN intensify our efforts. Please DONATE NOW by Credit Card at carryingcapacity.org. or by Check via U.S. mail to:
CCN’S
MAILING ADDRESS
Carrying
Capacity Network
P.O.BOX 457
San Francisco, CA 94104
Sincerely,
Carrying
Capacity Network,
Inc.
CarryingCapacity.org
CarryingCapacityNetwork.blogspot.com
CarryingCapacity.wordpress.com
Carrying
Capacity on ASAP-Coalition.org
Follow
CARRYING
CAPACITY on GAB: @CarryingCapacity &
Twitter: @CCNetworkOrg
--
Steve Camarota Discusses Housing Afghans in Hotels
Estimating the Illegal Immigrant Population Using the Current Population Survey
Related Articles
Republican State Legislators: Let’s Make Life Uncomfortable for Illegal Aliens
More from the Author
The Value of Foreign Degrees by Source Country
Why the Trump Administration Weakened Its Own Public Charge Rule
Defenders of the Public Charge Rule Have Their Day at the Supreme Court
The Center for Immigration Studies